Part
1: Where we started—excerpts from the comments to David Futrelle's
post
http://www.wehuntedthemammoth.com/2017/02/02/resisttrump-by-joining-a-local-indivisible-group-maybe/
guest:
Let
me talk a little here about the ‘invisible hand’. The Wealth of
Nations was published in 1776—at that time corporations were rare,
and only authorised individually by Parliament in specific cases for
specific purposes to benefit the public (if you’re interested,
Smith wrote that corporations should only be authorised for banking,
insurance, municipal water supply and transport infrastructure). They
were looked at suspiciously by Smith, Parliament, and everyone else
because at the time business and economics was all about personal
character, and corporations can hide personal character behind
collective anonymous ownership. When Adam Smith argued that people
acting selfishly are guided by an ‘invisible hand’ to promote the
public good, what he meant was that because, in order to gain access
to the marketplace, economic actors had to, I guess we would now say,
‘virtue signal’ to demonstrate their trustworthiness as business
partners, the stock of actual virtue in society would increase. At
the time Adam Smith was writing, to riff on Scildfreja’s point, the
economic and the social were not and could not be separated—Adam
Smith, whose other book is ‘The Theory of Moral Sentiments’,
would have been puzzled at the idea that they could.
@Scildfreja
It really does infuriate me that without exception interpreters of
Adam Smith are entirely ahistorical. We’re still learning to
appreciate the intricacies of what I refer to as the
cryptocapitalist economy of Georgian England, but that’s no excuse
not to recognise that the ‘capitalism’ Adam Smith writes about
in no way resembles the ‘capitalism’ of today. Interpreters are
ahistorical in terms of technology as well–his description of the
‘division of labour’ in a pin factory was actually a thought
experiment, as nothing like assembly line manufacture existed in
England until the early nineteenth century (the Venice Arsenal had
developed the technique a few hundred years earlier, but I’d be
surprised if Smith knew much about that as it was a military
secret–and in fact the first use of the technique in England was
also military). Anyway.
And
yes, in the first half of the nineteenth century corporations were
called ‘public’ businesses, as (as now) they were created by the
state, while sole proprietors and family businesses were referred to
as ‘private enterprise’. How corporations managed to sneak into
the ‘private enterprise’ tent, and thus gain ‘government
should leave us alone’ points, is a question I’m still trying to
answer (James Taylor, who has done a lot of insightful work in this
field, has one answer, I have another, both may be true).
Also
I know Adam Smith is a much bigger deal in the US than in
England–the English have pretty much never heard of him. When I
mention him in talks I typically get a sea of blank looks, so I
usually say ‘Adam Smith, you know, THE DUDE ON THE £20 NOTE’
and I swear half the audience reaches for their wallets to look.
(I’ve been told he’s on the £20 because he’s from Kirkaldy,
which is where Gordon Brown is from.)
And
I mean it when I say ‘without exception’–in preparation for
giving a talk specifically about Smith’s work at a conference a
few years ago I read pretty much everything written about him to
date, and not one single author relates his economic work to the
actual economy of the time, which is, of course, what Smith drew on
to develop his theories.
@Alan
It’s not that businesses felt a sense of public
responsibility–it’s that people were obligated to treat other
people fairly in business to ensure that they were treated fairly in
return. Craig Muldrew writes in The Economy of Obligation in 1998
that up to then historians had no real understanding of the scale of
the early modern economy–they postulated a low rate of economic
activity based on the fact that very little money circulated. What
Muldrew explained for his period, and what more of us now understand
is the case for later periods, is that the entire economic edifice
was built on personal credit. Say you and I do business with each
other. We meet once a year to settle up–I’ve provided you with
£100 worth of goods, and you’ve provided me with £101 worth of
goods–so I pay you £1. The £1 is visible, the rest of the
economic activity is not. That’s obviously a simple example; the
credit chains for an extraordinarily complex economy could be very
long, in space as well as in time. I’ve read lots of letters
saying things like ‘x owes me £y, and x’s friend z owes him £a,
so why doesn’t z pay me some portion of £a next time I see him
and I’ll credit x for that part of £y’.
This
kind of economic system can only work if the people involved know
and trust each other. I and others have done work on how personal
trust, which facilitated these kinds of informal credit
arrangements, was established and maintained. Many business
relationships were kin-related (people’s children married the
children of people in related businesses to establish trust links)
and religious (one of the explanations for the success of Quaker
businesses), but most were built up through personal reference and
association. One’s character was a marketable trait–if people
could vouch for you you had access to credit. I’ve seen lots and
lots of letters saying ‘I don’t do business with strangers–who
do we know in common, who can assure me that you’re trustworthy,
before I engage in a business relationship with you?’
As
business was all about relationships, and as these depended on one’s
character, if you couldn’t demonstrate to people you wanted to
have an economic relationship with that you were worthy of their
trust, by acting in a virtuous way, you wouldn’t have access to
their credit, and would thus be effectively ostracised from the
marketplace. ‘Long term relationships discouraged cheating; as
rumour of unfair dealings discouraged others from interacting with
their subject it was thus in everyone’s self-interest to act
honestly.’
Interestingly,
this ties into the history of money–a fantastic book about this is
David Graeber’s Debt: the first 5000 years. Money was originally
used only for taxes and religious offerings; Deborah Valenze, in The
social history of money, talks about how as late as the eighteenth
century it was still considered a little ‘dirty’ to exchange
money directly for goods and services, and the reliance on personal
credit and exchange gave the Georgian economy ‘an aura of
gifting’. Aside from extending long-term informal credit, people
maintained business relationships through exchanges of actual
gifts–of goods, services and information.
Oh
and speaking of credit–people in business wanted people to have
credit with them; credit was part of the relationship. We read a lot
in the literature of the time about people having ‘bills with
their tailors’ and whatnot–but this wasn’t necessarily a bad
or irresponsible thing. The example I use is this: say you and I are
friends. Over the years I’ve lent you a few books, and you’ve
lent me a few books. What if I suddenly come to your house with your
books and say ‘here, these are all the books of yours that I have,
I’m giving them back.’ The implication is that the friendship is
over–I no longer have any reason to see you again. Another example
is buying drinks at pubs–if I buy you a drink, and you don’t buy
me a drink this time, we’ll need to get together again so you can
buy me a drink. Outstanding credit is a way to maintain a
relationship.
The
economic system of peer to peer exchange based on credit facilitated
by long-term personal relationships, which I call cryptocapitalism,
has been generally ignored by historians–in my opinion it’s
because of Marx, whose four-level economic categorisation leaves
this stage out. (In writing this I’m realising that Marx himself
was observing and writing during the transition from
cryptocapitalism to modern capitalism–I’m not enough of an
expert on Marx to know how much of what he calls ‘capitalism’ is
the former rather than the latter; it would be a good research
question.) Scholars have identified aspects of this economy, but
have never drawn it out as a distinct system–E. P. Thompson does a
good job of describing parts of this economy in Customs in Common,
but as he is a Marxist he can’t really place it, referring to it
as a ‘transition period’ between feudalism and capitalism. (How
it can be seen as a transition when it resembles neither of these is
beyond me.) Some historians seem genuinely baffled by it–here’s
Gillian Cookson:
‘To
accept that some kind of collaboration operated, and apparently
worked well, requires an imaginative leap out of the competitive and
confrontational framework upon which much late-twentieth-century
management thinking rests. The evolution and success of the system
is explicable in the artisan context of early textile engineering.
Artisans generally took a long view of business, seeing continuation
as a priority so that following generations had the means to make a
living. This apparently anachronistic pre-industrial milieu provided
a highly suitable setting for the new industry.’
Rhuu:
@guest:
I honestly don’t understand how economists don’t get the
‘x owes me £y, and x’s friend z owes him £a, so why doesn’t z pay me some portion of £a next time I see him and I’ll credit x for that part of £y’.
bit.
Haven’t they ever had a large group of friends? I’m not
particularly fond of the idea, but it always seems to happen! You
make a group order from thinkgeek or something, then someone else
organises tickets to a concert, then someone ELSE organises a big
dinner where everyone is going to pitch in 5$ for ingredients. And
you’re like “OH, I’ll just pay 10$ because I owe 5$ for that
thinkgeek order, and cover that organiser. And we’ll be square!”
I
just never realised that that sort of thing would happen on a larger
scale, and be the basis of an economy.
Though
since it also happens organically in games like Catan or Bohnanza,
that makes total sense haha.
Thank
you for the lesson! Economics is something that seems so big, I
really don’t know much about it. I enjoyed the people aspect of it
as well.
guest:
Yes,
exactly–that’s just how a group of friends, who know and trust
each other, are connected through long-term relationships, and don’t
see any benefit out of ripping each other off, would behave. One of
my favourite research finds was a letter from someone who
manufactured parts for spinning machines to the owner of a canal
boat company–he wrote something like ‘hey, I ordered 40 pigs of
iron but you only dropped off 38 on Tuesday–could you have a root
around the bottom of the boat and bring me the other 2 when you find
them’–that’s how two people who have a personal as well as
business relationship interact. Informal mediation to settle
disputes was preferable to formal contracts or legal action–letters
like ‘you and I disagree how much I owe; let’s get two people we
respect to hear us out and decide.’ This is capitalism, but a very
different kind from what we see today.
Alan
Robertshaw:
You’re
really putting a lot of the stuff I do in context. What’s
especially interesting though is how much of what you mention still
goes on. It’s just not as apparent. But we have things like
‘without prejudice’ discussions, alternative dispute resolution,
and you may remember from some threads about the sharia courts how
the arbitration acts allow for parties just to choose someone all
sides trust to decide disputes and avoid the regular courts. It’s
not just small businesses either. The biggest users of ADR are the
oil companies. And those ‘Alice owes Bob, Bob owes Charlie, so
Alice can do something for Charlie’ solutions crop up a lot. It’s
ironic perhaps but barter, promises of future favours etc are really
common in big business. It avoids legal costs and there can be tax
advantages.
Trust
is still a major thing in commercial settings. One problem that I
often encounter is that there’ll be some hugely complex multi
million pound deal and absolutely no written record of it. It’s
all done on a handshake. That’s fine until something goes wrong.
Related
to that is that I’ve done more defamation cases for companies than
humans. Obviously corporations can’t suffer hurt feelings but they
can claim for loss of reputation. You might not be surprised to hear
that ‘imputations as to competence, honesty in business dealings
or creditworthiness’ are treated with particular seriousness in
law.
I swear I've read something about Smith in context in published stuff, maybe Ha-Joon Chang? My source amnesia is a constant trial.
ReplyDeleteAlso, thank you for the link, the Debt book is fascinating, and is helping me clarify a lot of thoughts I've been having over the years.
Am reading my first of Ha-Joon Chang's books now...dude is not endearing himself to me with his inaccurate economic views of immigration.....
DeleteAha--I've found what you were thinking of, in the intro to Economics: The User's Guide. Ha-Joon Chang is doing useful work, but he's not much of a historian, unfortunately--he does say 'capitalism in Smith's day was different from capitalism in our day', but (because this isn't what he's writing about) doesn't go on to consider, if that's the case, how Smith could have developed his ideas and what evidence he would have drawn from. Chang, like most economists, doesn't really understand what capitalism in Smith's day was all about (which, as I've said, is not surprising--it's not a field a lot of people are working in). His overview of Smith-era capitalism left out the entire 'middling sort' of people who were active in the peer-to-peer economy, the people Napoleon was referring to when he described the 'nation of shopkeepers'...and...Wikipedia tells me it was, in fact, Adam Smith who first used this phrase! And I've now reached economic history Inception.
DeleteThanks for that--I think I've run into Ha-Joon Chang before, but don't think he writes economic history as such, or specifically about Smith, so I wouldn't have included him in my background reading for the conference paper I was talking about--will go look up what he had to say about Georgian economics.
ReplyDelete